Discussion about this post

User's avatar
vk's avatar

The issues raised by this post are very important and extremely complex. They cannot be fully discussed in a comment section.

There are very serious Western scholars who consider Deng Xiaoping's reforms (which were actually not his, but the Party's; Deng only gave the general political direction to the reforms) a very similar form of NEP. I think this hypothesis is in the right direction and is certainly more true than the "China restored to capitalism" hypothesis that is dominant in the West nowadays. But it is incomplete.

It is crucial to have in mind that "China's NEP" was built on a very different -- much more favorable -- material base than the Soviet Union's. Most, if not all, of the modern-day Chinese capitalist class came from the poor/common peasantry, and they owe their position and status entirely to the socialist system. This is a totally different scenario because that means the Chinese capitalist class doesn't have a capitalist culture, set of ideas or political cohesion (organization). In the West, we have the old nobility who became the capitalist class or, in America, the nations were founded by capitalists (slaveowners), that is, the American nation-states were already born capitalist (liberal). During the Lenin era, the USSR had the problem of the kulak, rich peasants who owed their privileges to the czar's capitalist reforms of the 1860s and, by the time of his death, already had generations (life expectancy in Russia was extremely low; 64 years meant some four or five generations) of experience in ideology, politics and organization.

But Lenin's writings leave us a hole when we want to compare NEP with modern-day China. He died in early 1924. Later that year, the NEP got much deeper and worrisome, the capitalists seemingly taking over in a smooth and fast process. The situation was certainly worse than in today's China, many writings of the time giving socialism as finished. How the USSR managed to save socialism from NEP is one of the questions Edward Carr admits he didn't have an answer: he simply attributes it to sheer willpower of the Bolsheviks. Either way, if one wants to completely understand the NEP, one has to concentrate his or her studies in the years of 1924-1926, not 1923.

Besides, comparing Reform and Opening Up to the NEP doesn't answer the crucial question: why did NEP collapse in 1926-28, while R&OU is still alive and well today, more than 40 years later? Because few people in the West remind the fact that the NEP was never abolished from above: it collapsed under its own inner contradictions. The rise of Stalin (i.e. the rise of Socialism in One Country) only came after the fall of NEP, not during or before. It was the fall of NEP that created the vacuum SOC could fill, not the rise of SOC that imploded the NEP.

Expand full comment
Niko's avatar

I remember sitting in a Belgrade cafe with some Very Leftist Friends having a discussion somewhat like this. I had just read Mann's Buddenbrooks, his novel covering several generations of a German bourgeois merchant family. There's a scene in which a Buddenbrook (as burgermeister) has to confront a red mob of peasants and workers who demand a republic. 'You have a republic' is all he says in reply. It's a good illustration of the trench between radical social politics and 'dollar rationality.' The Buddenbrooks were businessmen and knew how to calculate costs, work shipping and trade, make deals, etc. etc. I realized reading that book that actually 'running the economy' (or even a minor import-export firm) is a kind of knowledge entirely different from the socialist point of view. I brought up all this to my well-meaning and battle-scarred friends, but they all kind of demurred (there was plenty of rakija, I admit) but still, no one had any reply to that point. It's kind of a big deal, too, for any leftist concerned with anything real...

Expand full comment
11 more comments...

No posts